sample
Haven't found the Essay You Want?
GET YOUR CUSTOM ESSAY SAMPLE
For Only $12.90/page

The Economic Impacts of Tourism Essay

ABSTRACT

Tourism has been criticised for having negative impacts on many of the destinations which tourists visit. There are considered to be three principal impacts – economic, environmental, & socio-cultural. This study looks at economic impacts and finds that although there are some negative aspects, most economic consequences of tourism are beneficial. These benefits include the effects of price and income elasticity, and also the economic consequences of tourism spending, including the generation of foreign exchange. This process stimulates the local economy through the multiplier effect, which can be direct, indirect, and induced. The article uses three tables to explain the multiplier, and policy implications are reviewed, using Turkish and Jamaican studies as reference points.

At the same time, the difficulties faced when calculating multipliers are considered, and also how multipliers in deflationary situations can turn from being positive to negative. Although the economic effects of tourism are usually held to outweigh tourisms economic benefits, the negatives can be significant. These negatives relate particularly to a likely increase in demand for imported goods once tourists begin to appear, revenue leakages out of the economy, over- dependence on tourism, and land value inflation. The study concludes that the economic benefits of tourism normally outweigh what negative features there may be. But it also acknowledges that the situation is much less clear-cut when considering environmental and socio-cultural issues as opposed to economic ones.

INTRODUCTION

Tourism is usually described as having three major types of impacts on many of the places which tourists visit (Cooper et al, 1993). These effects are economic, environmental, and socio-cultural in nature (and some people have mentioned political consequences also). However, some impacts have been attributed to tourism though they may in fact originate elsewhere. Instead, more appropriate sources may be the media, the advertising & fashion industries, new industrial development, urbanisation, modern agriculture, mining and forestry projects, and government and military activity. But while all these factors can be described as frequent features of modern societies, it is widely believed that travel and tourism do generate impacts, including economic ones.

BENEFICIAL ECONOMIC IMPACTS

Unlike some of its environmental and socio-cultural effects, tourisms economic impacts are mainly considered to be beneficial. These are:
* the generation of foreign exchange,
* the creation of new job and employment opportunities,
* the stimulation of trade, income and entrepreneurship – especially in the service and small business sectors,
* the provision of new infrastructure which is available for non-tourism uses,
* increased regional development – particularly in isolated areas,
* greater tax revenues permitting greater government spending – or reduced taxes on other activities, and
* the operation of what is called the multiplier effect.

Price and Income Elasticity

Leisure tourism is considered to be price and income elastic (Cooper et al, 1993), and therefore very responsive to economic conditions in both host and traveller-generating countries (eg USA & Japan). Price decreases and increases in destination countries (eg Thailand & Malaysia) are likely to, respectively, encourage or discourage some tourists from the traveller-generating countries (who would otherwise have visited) from coming. Similarly, income rises and income falls will have a parallel effect, respectively encouraging or discouraging overseas visiting by citizens of the traveller-generating nations.

The Economic Impacts of Tourists Spending

The economic effects of visitors presence at destinations arise from the fact that travellers and tourists spend their money on a wide variety of goods and services. This expenditure can be seen as an injection of financial resources into the host economy, thereby creating new levels of consumer demand.

Foreign Exchange

Foreign tourists change their foreign currency (usually a ‘hard’ or fully convertible one) into the local currency to pay for their tourism experience. As a result, the host country now has more foreign currency to spend on its own needs, such as providing better medical and educational facilities, and/or stimulating general economic development etc. At the same time, in balance of payments terms, tourism expenditure is viewed as being equivalent to export income for traveller-receiving countries, eg Thailand and Indonesia. Conversely, tourism expenditure amounts to an import cost for visitor-generating countries.

Measuring Economic Impacts

However, the measurement of the economic impacts of tourism is far more complicated than simply calculating the total amount of all such tourists expenditure, or their related receipts. Such calculations take no account of how much tourist expenditure leaks out of the economy either in payment for imported goods and services to satisfy tourists needs, or as taxes and savings. Nor does it account for how much additional expenditure is created through the cascading effect of money being re-spent again and again by different people and businesses throughout a particular economy (Cooper et al, 1993).

Direct, Indirect and Induced Multiplier Effects

The cascading effect of tourists money being spent throughout the host economy, begins at front-line tourist establishments, eg hotels, restaurants and taxis. The effect of this spending then permeates throughout the economy (Mathieson & Wall, 1982), creating impacts at three different levels: ie at the direct, indirect, and induced levels.. This is the multiplier effect. The direct level of impact (also called the direct multiplier) is the value of tourist spending less the value of imports necessary to supply the front- line service-providers, such as hotels, etc. The direct impact – and the size of this multiplier – is likely to be less than an individual tourists actual expenditure because of leakage, except in the rare cases where the local economy can supply all that particular tourists needs (Cooper et al, 1993).

Those travel industry businesses which directly receive the tourists money also need to purchase goods and services from other organisations within the local economy. The economic activity generated by these subsequent rounds of expenditure is called the indirect multiplier effect. The indirect effect will not involve all that money which was originally spent by tourists, as some of this money is also likely to leak out of circulation through imports, savings, and taxes. Finally, during the direct and indirect rounds of expenditure, money will be paid to local residents in the form of wages, salaries, rent, interest, and dividends; and also to local businesses for routine services.

Some of this expenditure (called the induced multiplier) generates yet more rounds of economic activity – by being spent on local goods and services. It is only when all three levels of impact (ie direct + indirect + induced) are assessed that the full nature of this particular effect of tourism can be identified. In the multiplier process, direct multipliers flow from what visitors actually spend, while indirect multipliers are created by tourist industry expenditure. Induced multipliers come from the routine spending, by their non-tourism industry suppliers, of both their direct tourist and indirect tourist industry receipts.

This is because secondary data is seldom available in sufficient quantities to enable an accurate calculation to be made of what a particular area, or industry sectors, actual multiplier is. In addition, the first requirement for any primary data survey is that there are full records of every transaction. In fact, there seldom are as some transactions, especially restaurant tips and some taxi fares, may be cash-in-hand. Even if all transactions have been recorded, an essential requirement for accuracy is that every item of expenditure in an appropriately designed sample can be correctly analysed.

This is needed to permit each purchase to be confidently categorised as either tourist expenditure (ie by consumers or the industry), or as spending by non-tourists. Finally, supply constraints can invalidate the accuracy of a multiplier analysis, if the local tourism industrys existing capacity is inadequate to meet the additional demand created by the multiplier effect. In addition, if there is insufficient extra labour available, then increased tourism expenditure is more likely to generate inflation than increased economic activity, and possibly also a demand for more imported goods and services.

Problems with Employment Multipliers

Similarly, great care is required when interpreting employment multipliers. Employment levels do not necessarily grow at the same pace as income or output does. Indeed increases (or decreases) in the level of tourist expenditure are seldom matched immediately by changes in the number of people employed. Much depends on the extent to which the existing labour force in each sector is fully utilized, and the degree to which labour is able to transfer between different occupations, and sections of the economy.

When the Multiplier can be Deflationary

Just as extra expenditures stimulate further spending through the multiplier effect, reductions of routine expenditure can have a reverse effect. For example, if normal spending is significantly curtailed, the beneficial effects of the tourism multiplier (normally widely felt throughout most economies) may actually be deflationary. This occurs because more and more of those businesses, which are dependent on tourism, can no longer spend at their previous levels. Consequently, their suppliers now also have less to spend – and therefore have to deliberately limit their expenditure too. Naturally, this situation becomes more severe if some of them begin to face cash flow crises, or even bankruptcy – so further deepening the recession.

NEGATIVE ECONOMIC IMPACTS

Although travel and tourism studies tend mainly to emphasise the beneficial features of tourisms economic impacts, there are some negative consequences also to consider. These are:

* leakages of expenditure out of the local economy,
* increased propensities (ie tendencies) to import,
* opportunity costs,
* displacement effects,
* over-dependence on tourism,
* inflation and higher land values,
* seasonality issues,
* over-reliance on expatriat labour,
* creation of new or extra costs, and
* problems over foreign capital investment.

An Increased Propensity to Import

Growing tourist numbers may lead to increasing import requirements. According to Mathieson & Wall (1982), the demands by some tourists for their home comforts while on overseas holidays, especially for food and drinks from their home country, can impose extra costs on host countries by requiring them to import these items for resale to the visitors. This is especially so with small island economies which often do not produce locally what the tourists want – not just the food and drink brands that the visitors prefer, but also luxury purchases such as jewellery, cameras, and photographic equipment etc.

Leakage

The revenue loss, which accompanies the spending of newly-acquired foreign exchange on buying foreign goods for re-sale to tourists, is called leakage. Other forms of leakage include savings, which are either not spent by anyone for a long time and just hoaded for the future, or lent by banks – but not necessarily in or near the tourism locality where they were earned. In the latter situation, the country benefits, as do the people living where the money is finally spent, but not the original community who actually hosted the tourists.

Opportunity Costs

Every item of tourism expenditure in theory could have been spent on some other project, inevitably raising the question of which is more important: eg the new hotel, or a new stretch of road, a hospital, or a school etc. Similarly, the production of goods and services for tourism purposes requires the allocation of resources which could also have been used for other, perhaps more socially laudable, purposes. The opportunity cost in such situations is the cost of using scarce resources for tourism, either as consumption or development, as opposed to using the money for alternative, perhaps more socially preferable, purposes.

Displacement Effects

Displacement can happen when a tourism development occurs at the expense of another industry, or when a new tourism project takes customers away from an existing attraction or facility – rather than adding sufficient numbers of new visitors to the local tourist destination to justify the investment. This type of situation, where tourism development simply substitutes one form of expenditure and economic activity for another, is known as the displacement effect.

Over-dependence on Tourism

Anywhere, whether it is a town or a country, is in an economically vulnerable position when it is dependent on the health and vigour of just one industry. This also applies when tourism is the principal industry (Mathieson & Wall, 1982). Indeed, tourism revenues may fluctuate, for more than just seasonal reasons, beyond a destination or an attractions ability to predict and manage such a situation.

Inflation and Higher Land Values

Prices frequently rise, including land and property values, when there is sustained building demand for tourism facilities. However, a boom atmosphere at a destination frequently leads to over-investment in accommodation stock; and later, usually a fall in some buildings prices.

Seasonality

Revenue and income flows usually vary with the seasons. Peak season visitor numbers can at some destinations and attractions exceed their quietest periods attendance figures by many times. This can even be by a factor of more than a hundred between a cold, wet UK January day (9 visitors) and a sunny UK mid-summer day (1500 + people), according to Glastonbury Abbeys (UK) management staff (Harcombe DPT, 1997). Consequently, the decision as to what the maximum number of customers that an attraction or tourist facility should cater for is a difficult one, especially for large hotels and theme parks – because of seasonal demand, and the need to ensure an adequate return on their investment. Too few beds or restaurant tables etc may mean customers are turned away in the high season. At the same time, excessive over-capacity in the low season means near-empty premises – even though the organisation still faces substantial fixed costs.

Use of Expatriat Labour.

In some newly emerging economies, where there is a strongly perceived need for rapid economic and social development, the management of many of the new tourism facilities may initially be by expatriat staff (Mathieson & Wall, 1982). But their whole purpose of working there may be to repatriat most of their savings from this work back to their home countries – another form of leakage. Additionally, the expatriats may not aways train local people adequately enough for them to take over, so perpetuating the foreignerspresence. A problem that has sometimes emerged, especially in the Gulf countries, is that tourism may be a reasonably high status occupation (because of the fun element to it), but hospitality may not be. Consequently, the educated local elites may be unkeen to learn hotel and catering work. Instead they may prefer to receive the profits from the hospitality businesses they own, while employing foreign staff to do the actual work.

Creation of Extra and/or New Costs

More tourists mean new or increased requirements for utility production and/or facilities, such as water, electricity, and gas supplies, and sewage and garbage removal. In addition, the tourism facilities and attractions will need routine repair and maintenance. So also will all the related infrastructure, especially roads; and also any other transportation links and facilities that may be necessary, including railways, air and/or water links.

Foreign Capital Investment

Investment in tourism and transport plant (eg airports, roads, railways, and hotels etc) can be very expensive, and may require foreign investment. However, profits will almost inevitably leak out, in such cases, to investors in investing countries. Indeed, many investors will not wish to invest in any less developed tourist-receiving countries unless – quite understandably – they can be sure they can redeem their profits in, or sell their business there for, hard currency.

CONCLUSION

Tourism clearly provides a significant number of beneficial economic impacts to any country or locality which receives a steady flow of visitors. International visitors are a valuable source of foreign currency. At the same time, the spending of both domestic and foreign visitors produces a cascading effect of new money through the economy via the multiplier effect. Enterprise is stimulated, and new jobs created, together contributing to increased government revenue. But there are some negative factors also to be considered. These particularly concern leakages of expenditure out of the economy, pressures for increased imports, and new utility and infrastructural costs.

Also relevant are possible inflationary effects, the problems of over-dependency on a major industry (ie tourism) and also, initially at least, on ex-patriat labour, as well as issues relating to foreign capital investment, seasonality, opportunity costs and displacement effects. In balance, the economic impacts of tourism are usually considered to be beneficial for countries and localities looking for sustained growth. It is in the field of tourisms environmental and socio-cultural impacts where the real controversies lie. Tourisms environmental and socio-cultural impacts are usually considered to have a number of positives to offset some, at least, of travels allegedly negative effects. However, they may not always be able to do so with the same confidence that tourisms economic impacts can. Indeed, it is these two impact categories where most of the criticisms which are levelled at tourism can be found.

REFERENCES

Mathieson A & Wall G; Tourism: economic, physical and social impacts, Longman, Harlow, UK, 1982. Cooper C, Fletcher J, Gilbert D, & Wanhill S; Tourism: principles & practice, Longman, Harlow, UK, 1993. Inskeep E; Tourism planning: an integrated and sustainable development approach, Van Nostrand Reinhold, New York, 1991. Gee CY, Makens JC, & Choy DJL; The travel industry, Van Nostrand Reinhold, New York, 1989. Fletcher J; The economic impact of international tourism on the national economy of Jamaica, unpublished report to the government of Jamaica, USAID/UNDP/WTO, 1985. Harcombe DPT; The marketing of legends, with particular reference to the King Arthur legend, unpublished MSc thesis, Bournemouth University, UK,
1997. Diamond J; Tourism and developmental policy: a quantitive appraisal, Bulletin of Tourism Research vol 28 no 1 pp 36 � 50, 1976. Holloway JC & Robinson C; Marketing for tourism, Longman, Harlow, UK, 1995. Mill RC; Tourism: the international business, Prentice Hall International, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, USA, 1990. Mill RC & Morrison AM; The tourism system: an introductory text, Prentice Hall International, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey, USA, 1992.

* The main positive economic impacts of tourism relate to foreign exchange earnings, contributions to government revenues, generation of employment and business opportunities. Some of the most important economic benefits that tourism brings along are mentioned here. .

Foreign exchange earnings

Tourism expenditures, the export and import of related goods and services generate income to the host economy. Tourism is a main source of foreign exchange earnings for at least 38 % of all countries

Contribution to government revenues

Government revenues from the tourism sector can be categorised as direct and indirect contributions. Direct contributions are generated by taxes on incomes from tourism employment, tourism businesses and by direct charges on tourists such as eco tax or departure taxes. Indirect contributions derive from taxes and duties on goods and services supplied to tourists, for example, taxes on souvenirs, alcohol, restaurants, etc.

Employment generation

The rapid expansion of international tourism has led to significant employment creation. For example, the hotel accommodation sector alone provided around 11.3 million jobs worldwide in 1995. Tourism can generate jobs directly through hotels, restaurants, taxis, souvenir sales and indirectly through the supply of goods and services needed by tourism-related businesses. According to the World Tourism Organisation tourism represents around 7 % of the world’s employees.

Stimulation of infrastructure investment

Tourism can induce the local government to improve the infrastructure by creating better water and sewage systems, roads, electricity, telephone and public transport networks. All this can improve the quality of life for residents as well as facilitate tourism.

Contribution to local economies

Tourism can be a significant or even an essential part of the local economy. Because environment is a basic component of the tourism industry’s assets, tourism revenues are often used to measure the economic value of protected areas. There are other local revenues that are not easily quantified, as not all tourist expenditures are formally registered in the macro-economic statistics. Part of the tourism income comes from informal employment, such as street vendors and informal guides. The positive side of informal or unreported employment is that the money is returned to the local economy and has a great multiplier effect as it is spent over and over again. The World Travel and Tourism Council estimates that tourism generates an indirect contribution equal to 100 % of direct tourism expenditures.

Tourism can contribute directly to the conservation of sensitive areas and habitats. Revenue from park-entrance fees and similar sources can be allocated specifically to pay for the protection and management of environmentally sensitive areas. Some governments collect money in more far-reaching and indirect ways that are not linked to specific parks or conservation areas. User fees, income taxes, taxes on sales or rental of recreation equipment and license fees for activities such as hunting and fishing can provide governments with the funds needed to manage natural resources.

Questions in Economics
* Economic Way of Thinking?
* If a dollar ripped in half, does it still have value?
* Why do business men refuse to apply for bank loans during economic depressions?


Essay Topics:


Sorry, but copying text is forbidden on this website. If you need this or any other sample, we can send it to you via email. Please, specify your valid email address

We can't stand spam as much as you do No, thanks. I prefer suffering on my own